Frontier Economics Logo

Infrastructure Partnerships Australia (IPA) and the Water Services Association of Australia (WSAA) jointly released a report today entitled “Doing the important, as well as the urgent: reforming the urban water sector”.

The report is a call for national policy leadership regarding urban water, and argues that this would elevate urban water policy above the urgent decisions made amidst a crisis—allowing instead for an approach based on good governance, long term planning and greater responsiveness to customer preferences.

The three central recommendations focus around better economic regulation, appropriate opportunities to deploy competition and clarification of governance arrangements. In particular, economic regulation is currently varied throughout the states, and the report suggests a nationally consistent framework would promote competition, provide the right incentives to businesses and improve choice and services for consumers.

Frontier (Australia) advises many clients in the water sector and assisted the IPA and WSAA in the development of the report.

For more information, please contact Marita O’Keeffe on m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

Rob Francis, Associate Director at Frontier (Europe), spoke at the Essential Services Commission of Victoria (ESC) Water Pricing conference on 9 and 10 November in Melbourne. The two-day event was attended by representatives from water utilities and regulators across Australia. The purpose of the event was to share ideas on options to reform the regulation of water prices in Victoria.

Rob presented two papers. On the first day, he presented the findings on Frontier’s study for the ESC on options for regulating water prices. The study evaluates the alternative methods available for regulating prices and provides a high level assessment of their applicability to the water sector in Victoria. On the second day, he presented the analysis from a paper prepared for Wessex Water on the scope to introduce direct negotiation between customers and the utility as part of the regulatory process. The paper describes the different types of negotiation and considers the cases where negotiation is most likely to be effective.

Following the ESC conference, Rob and colleagues from Frontier (Australia) ran several in-depth roundtable forums for regulators and water businesses in Melbourne and Sydney.

Frontier regularly advises water utilities and regulators on issues relating to regulatory reform.

For more information, please contact Marita O'Keeffe at m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

 

In August 2015, the Australian Government proposed a CO2 emissions target of a 26%-28% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2030. More recently, the Government released draft details around the Direct Action Safeguards Mechanism. Because many expect that Direct Action is the main course to meeting Australia’s appetite for abatement, some were disappointed when the Safeguards Mechanism was served up and fear we will struggle to meet our emissions targets by 2030.

However, it seems that the Government only intends the Safeguards (and Direct Action) to be a tapas dish with several more policy dishes still to be served, each contributing to meeting our 2030 abatement challenge. And after all these domestic abatement policy dishes are served, even if it still looks like Australia may go hungry (not meet our future emissions targets) the potential to recognise international abatement credits could potentially loom as the kebab at the end of the night.DOWNLOAD FULL PUBLICATION

In an earlier bulletin, Uber Regulated? we examined the case for regulating so-called “sharing economy” services, like Uber and Airbnb. In this companion piece, we discuss why it is important to understand the economic value likely to be created by these services. Gains to the community from regulatory reform largely hinge on new services filling gaps in existing services, and creating new sources of demand, rather than substituting for existing services. These gains should be the focus of government attention when thinking about to whether to regulate to ‘level the playing field’.

Governments face a dilemma about whether and how to regulate new services that use digital technology to disrupt existing service provision models. By lowering costs to consumers and sellers and crafting new mechanisms to promote trust, these services are unlocking value in existing infrastructure. This provides new consumption opportunities to people who would otherwise not consume, or allows existing users to consume in new and better ways. However, providers of these new services often bypass existing regulations and taxes paid by firms offering similar services in the ‘old economy’. Critics of the new services argue that avoiding regulation is the primary reason for their success.Uber is currently at the vanguard of this battle. The ‘ride sharing’ service – which is essentially a pre-booked taxi service – has entered many markets even where its drivers and vehicles are not licensed under prevailing transport laws. This enables Uber’s drivers to avoid certain licensing costs (and potentially other costs such as taxes) faced by existing firms.

Governments investigating the need for regulatory change are faced with two options:

In a previous bulletin, Uber regulated, we analysed the impact of technology on regulation, and suggested that government’s role should be limited to ensuring that vehicles and drivers operate safely.But, in markets where incumbents have a lot to lose, our prescription is easier said than done. Existing regulations are politically or financially costly to unwind. In the case of Uber, this is often due to the restrictive licensing of taxis, so new entry can create large losses for existing licence holders.In this bulletin, we argue that good policy decisions require an understanding of what we are giving up by insisting on levelling the playing field. Even if governments do so through a sense of fairness to incumbents, can we estimate what benefits the community might miss out on?

Increasing The Size Of The Pie

A useful insight from economic analysis is that there is a difference between entry that substitutes for existing services and entry that creates demand that was never there before. This difference is reflected in how we measure the economic value that is created.

Economic value is defined as the difference between the willingness to pay of the buyer and the willingness to sell (the cost) of the seller. Where substitution occurs, we measure the value of the new service compared to the existing service. Where additional demand is created, we measure the value of the new service against the additional costs of its supply.

Applied to taxis and ride sharing, we measure the effect of substitution by comparing the value to consumers and taxi operators of existing trips with trips taken with new entrants like Uber. Gains from substitution therefore hinge on an increased willingness to pay for existing services, or lower costs.

Increased willingness to pay for Uber’s service, where it substitutes for an existing taxi service, is certainly possible. Consumers clearly value Uber’s technology and improved controls over driver quality. Nonetheless, given the similarity of the underlying service to a taxi service, these gains are likely to be relatively small.

On the costs side, Uber may have lower costs as it avoids the payment of licence fees, which can account for between 10 and 20 per cent of total taxi revenues. However, other sources of cost advantage are less clear. Uber takes 20 per cent of each fare, while drivers keep the remaining 80 per cent. Most other costs, such as the driver’s labour, vehicle and fuel costs, will be similar for taxis and Uber. For example, the Australian Tax Office is now insisting that Uber’s drivers are subject to the same tax requirements as taxi drivers. So, it is not certain that Uber will have significant sustainable cost advantages.

Now consider the change in economic value if demand across taxis and Uber vehicles expands. The change in value is no longer the simple value of an Uber trip over a taxi trip, but instead the gap between consumer willingness to pay for more rides and the additional cost of supplying that service. It is not hard to imagine that at certain times, this value could be very large. Indeed, Uber’s ‘surge pricing’ is a means of capturing some of that very high willingness to pay at certain times.

It is good public policy to implement reforms whose benefits exceed their costs – that is, those reforms that create economic value – even if those reforms create losers.[1] A central focus of the case for reform should therefore be the relative size of these demand expansion and substitution effects.

Why Availability Is The Key To A Bigger Pie

To estimate demand expansion, we first need to identify where it comes from. Lower prices are one source. Given that Uber’s costs are somewhat lower, this is likely to be a modest source of new demand. In our view, the more promising and sustainable source of new demand is through better service quality.

We refer here to service ‘quality’ in a broad sense: it includes dimensions like driver and vehicle quality; ease of use; and service availability. The innovative technologies used by new services like Uber have significant potential to improve driver and vehicle quality and ease of use. And increased availability alone seems a significant potential source of gain, even in the absence of other quality improvements.

The nexus between better vehicle availability and market expansion is likely to be strongest under two conditions: if there are restrictions on vehicle availability, and if there are high fixed costs of vehicle or driver entry.

If there is an under-supply of existing vehicles, consumers will be more responsive to greater availability. This has both a short-term and a longer-term element. In the short-term, the gains from availability will be higher if demand is peaked and consumers have a relatively high willingness-to-pay in these periods. If peak supply has been heavily restricted by regulation, the benefits to consumers from additional supply via a new service could be very large. The longer-term benefit comes from the ability of taxis and other vehicles to act as viable alternatives to private cars. Many modern cities are dominated by private cars, so that even small changes in availability and reliability of ride services could increase the feasibility of longer-term switching away from private cars (see Box 1).

If peak supply has been heavily restricted by regulation, the benefits to consumers from additional supply via a new service could be very large.

The second condition is that regulations impose high fixed costs of entry. This might be due to licensing restrictions imposed on vehicles or drivers. These high fixed costs limit the overall number of vehicles and drivers that can profitably drive, and means it is harder to increase supply at certain high demand times. If, in contrast, entry costs were low, the costs of entry may be recovered from driving only a small number of peak hours. This is when the demand expansion effects are greatest. Moreover, this means that vehicles will not be on the road in lower demand periods, when availability of vehicles is valued less by consumers, and trip substitution is likely to dominate.

The two market expansion conditions suggest that the benefits from reform will be different in every market. Taxi markets in Australia, the United States and in some parts of Europe have historically been subject to restrictive licensing policies, which both raise the costs of entry and reduce supply at peak times. This suggests that, a priori, benefits from better availability could be very large. Other markets are less restrictive. In these circumstances, quantification of different effects is highly desirable.Research conducted for the Victorian Taxi Industry Inquiry in 2012 found that the primary source of substitution for taxis in Melbourne was private cars. This reflected the extremely high mode share of private car journeys. This is illustrated in the Figure. For a taxi price fall of 10%, the research predicts that most demand captured by taxis will be a result of fewer car journeys – even though hire cars were perceived by consumers to be a closer substitute. As private cars undertake over 80% of journeys, even a small change in mode share leads to large increases in taxi journeys.

Taking Up The Measurement Challenge

Forecasting the impact of regulatory changes on demand in a particular market is difficult, particularly as (in our experience) jurisdictions only rarely have access to detailed demand data that is held by taxi companies and new entrants. Nonetheless, a number of data sources can be used to estimate market expansion and substitution effects in particular markets.

A crude measure of impact might come from changes in taxi licence values. Tradeable taxi licences trade at prices that reflect the value that can be earned in operating taxi services. A reduction in value may indicate a substitution effect. That being said, changes in the value of perpetual licences occur for a range of reasons unrelated to taxi demand, so this is not likely to prove conclusive.[2]

A better estimate might come from direct inferences based on markets where entry by Uber (and its competitors) has occurred. For example, a recent analysis of trip data from New York, which has restrictive entry regulation, allows some inferences to be drawn. Across the greater New York area, the data suggest that for every 100 trips taken in an Uber vehicle, 65 were substituted from taxis. The remaining 35 were either entirely new trips or had substituted from other forms of transport.[3] Further analysis also revealed substantial variations across time and location. In outer boroughs that have traditionally been poorly-serviced by the famous yellow taxis, this figure was quite different. Of 100 Uber trips in these areas, 80 represented new trips while only around 20 were substitutes for taxi trips.

Using some assumptions, data like that collected in New York can be used to estimate directly the likely gains in consumer value from new entry. This analysis could be further improved by using trip data in conjunction with other data to directly estimate the price sensitivity (elasticity) of taxi services and potential substitute services. Greater increases in consumer value will be associated with less elastic demand for new services, as it indicates higher willingness to pay.

A third source of data is consumer survey data. These data can be particularly helpful as they are market specific, and does not rely on existing data sources. Surveying can range from simple questioning of alternatives to questionnaires designed to gather data for the application of statistical analysis. Such techniques can be used on survey data to estimate either demand systems, which provides evidence on the sensitivity of consumers to lower prices and more availability, or to estimate willingness to pay for new services directly.[4]

Levelling Up Rather Than Levelling Out

Modernising regulation to fit with recent technological innovations is a challenging task. It is tempting, but not entirely helpful, to postulate a world in which regulation does not exist. A more modest objective would be to maximise the value created by new services, and resist ‘levelling the playing field’ if that will undermine these benefits.

If policy is to be evidence-based, then the question of substitution or market expansion is where our attention should be squarely focused.

We suggest that the big gains to the community will occur if new services can fill gaps in existing services, and create new sources of demand. Quantifying these gains is undoubtedly difficult, but if policy is to be evidence-based, then the question of substitution or market expansion is where our attention should be squarely focused.

DOWNLOAD FULL PUBLICATION

[1] A separate policy question arises as to whether the ‘winners’ from reform should compensate the losers.[2] An example is that licence values are affected by the rate at which future profits are discounted. This rate depends on alternative rates of interest in the economy.[3] The Economist, Taxis vs Uber: Substitutes or Complements, August 10 2015, available at: http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2015/08/taxis-v-uber[4] For an example of the first kind of survey, see Victorian Taxi Industry Inquiry, Draft Report: Customers First, May 2012, pp. 439-440.

An earlier bulletin from Frontier (Australia) Uber regulated? examined the case for regulating so-called “sharing economy” services, like Uber and Airbnb.

In a new bulletin published today, we discuss why it is important to understand the economic value likely to be created by these services. Gains to the community from regulatory reform largely hinge on new services filling gaps in existing services, and creating new sources of demand, rather than substituting for existing services. These gains should be the focus of government attention when thinking about to whether to regulate to ‘level the playing field’.

Frontier (Australia) regularly advises clients on issues in the taxi industry, as well as in the transport sector more broadly.

For more information, please contact Marita O'Keeffe at m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

The Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) today released its final decision on the prices that other operators pay to use Telstra’s copper network to provide telecommunications services to consumers.

The final decision will require a one-off uniform fall of 9.4 per cent in access prices from current levels for the seven fixed line access services. The new prices will apply from 1 November 2015 until 30 June 2019.

The ACCC dealt with a number of difficult and complex issues during the inquiry, including:

Frontier (Australia) advised a number of access seekers to Telstra’s network during this review, providing submissions on the appropriate treatment of NBN payments, cost and demand forecasts, cost allocation and price structure.

For more information, please contact Marita O’Keeffe on m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

In August 2015, the Australian Government proposed a CO2 emissions target of a 26%-28% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2030. More recently, the Government released draft details around the Direct Action Safeguards Mechanism. Frontier (Australia) looks at this policy in a new report for clients.

Because many expect that Direct Action is the main course to meeting Australia’s appetite for abatement, some were disappointed when the Safeguards Mechanism was served up and fear we will struggle to meet our emissions targets by 2030.

However, it seems that the Government only intends the Safeguards (and Direct Action) to be a tapas dish with several more policy dishes still to be served, each contributing to meeting our 2030 abatement challenge. And after all these domestic abatement policy dishes are served, even if it still looks like Australia may go hungry (not meet our future emissions targets), the potential to recognise international abatement credits could potentially loom as the kebab at the end of the night.

Frontier regularly advises clients on a range of climate change issues.

For more information,  please contact Marita O’Keeffe at m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

Australia’s current carbon emissions target for 2020 is a 5% reduction on 2000 levels. It is highly likely that existing policy settings will see this target achieved. In the coming months, world attention will turn to Australia’s carbon emissions targets beyond 2020. The Government has proposed a target of a 26%-28% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2030. In our view, a 25% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2025 (36% by 2030) would not only be achievable, but comparable with the proposals of other nations.

This report by Frontier (Australia) provides some context for comparing these targets and tasks.DOWNLOAD FULL PUBLICATION

 

The Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) today announced that it will not oppose TPG Telecom Limited’s (TPG) proposed acquisition of iiNet Limited (iiNet). TPG and iiNet are two of the five largest suppliers of fixed broadband in Australia.

In June of this year, the ACCC had released a Statement of Issues (SOI) concerning the proposed acquisition. The SOI had stated that the ACCC’s market enquiries had disclosed concerns about the proposed acquisition. During its subsequent investigation both the Commission and Frontier (Australia) (retained by iiNet) undertook modelling of the likely upward pricing pressure (UPP) that the proposed merger might cause.

The ACCC concluded that the acquisition would not reach the threshold of a ‘substantial’ lessening of competition as required under section 50 of the Competition and Consumer Act.

Frontier (Australia) regularly advises both carriers and regulators on competition issues in the telecommunications sector.

For more information, please contact Marita O'Keeffe at m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

 

Australia’s current carbon emissions target for 2020 is a 5% reduction on 2000 levels. It is highly likely that existing policy settings will see this target achieved. In the coming months, world attention will turn to Australia’s carbon emissions targets beyond 2020. The Australian Government has today proposed a target of a 26%-28% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2030.

Frontier (Australia) today released a report looking at Australia’s proposed emissions targets. In our view, a 25% reduction on 2005 emissions levels by 2025 (36% by 2030) would not only be achievable, but comparable with the proposals of other nations. Our report provides some context for comparing these targets and tasks.

For more information, please contact m.okeeffe@frontier-economics.com.au or phone +61 3 9620 4488.

 

menuchevron-down